Example: Consider any price below $6, such as $5:
Qd=5Qs=2
Qd>Qs: excess demand
A shortage of 3 units
Example: Consider any price below $6, such as $5:
Qd=5Qs=2
Qd>Qs: excess demand
A shortage of 3 units
Sellers will not supply more than 2 units
For 2 units, some buyers are willing to pay more than $5
Example: Consider any price below $6, such as $5:
Qd=5Qs=2
Qd>Qs: excess demand
A shortage of 3 units
Buyers will raise their bids against one another, raising the price
At higher prices, sellers are willing to supply more!
Continues until equilibrium, no pressure for change, qs=qd
Example: Consider any price above $6, such as $8:
Qd=2;Qs=8
Qd<Qs: excess supply
A surplus of 6 units
Example: Consider any price above $6, such as $8:
Qd=2;Qs=8
Qd<Qs: excess supply
A surplus of 6 units
Buyers will not buy more than 2 units
For 2 units, some sellers are willing to accept less than $8
Example: Consider any price above $6, such as $8:
Qd=2;Qs=8
Qd<Qs: excess supply
A surplus of 6 units
Sellers will lower their asking prices against one another, lowering the price
At lower prices, buyers are willing to buy more!
Continues until equilibrium, no pressure for change, qs=qd
Supply function and demand function relate quantity (supplied or demanded) to price only
Certainly there are many other factors that influence how much a buyer or seller will purchase at a particular price!
A supply or demand function (or graph) requires "ceterus paribus" (all else equal)
qDx=D(m,px,py)
See Class 1.7 for a reminder.
A change in one of the "determinants of demand" (or "shifters") will shift the demand curve
Shows up in (inverse) demand function by a change in the intercept (choke price)!
See my Visualizing Demand Shifters
See Class 1.9 for a reminder.
Consider our demand function: qD=10−p
If the market price (p) changes (perhaps because supply changes), that results in a change in quantity demanded (qD)
Ceterus paribus has not been violated
Consider our demand function: qD=10−p
If the something other than price changes (income, preferences, price of a complement, etc), that results in a change in demand
qD=12−p
More individuals want to buy more of the good at every price
Entire demand curve shifts to the right
More individuals want to buy more of the good at every price
Entire demand curve shifts to the right
At the original market price, a shortage! (qD>qS)
More individuals want to buy more of the good at every price
Entire demand curve shifts to the right
At the original market price, a shortage! (qD>qS)
Some buyers willing to pay more at this quantity
More individuals want to buy more of the good at every price
Entire demand curve shifts to the right
At the original market price, a shortage! (qD>qS)
Some buyers willing to pay more at this quantity
Buyers raise bids, inducing sellers to sell more
Reach new equilibrium with:
Fewer individuals want to buy less of the good at every price
Entire demand curve shifts to the left
Fewer individuals want to buy less of the good at every price
Entire demand curve shifts to the left
At the original market price, a surplus! (qD<qS)
Fewer individuals want to buy less of the good at every price
Entire demand curve shifts to the left
At the original market price, a surplus! (qD<qS)
Some sellers willing to accept less at this quantity
Fewer individuals want to buy less of the good at every price
Entire demand curve shifts to the left
At the original market price, a surplus! (qD<qS)
Some sellers willing to accept less at this quantity
Sellers lower asks, inducing buyers to buy more
Reach new equilibrium with:
More individuals want to sell more of the good at every price
Entire supply curve shifts to the right
More individuals want to sell more of the good at every price
Entire supply curve shifts to the right
At the original market price, a surplus! (qD<qS)
More individuals want to sell more of the good at every price
Entire supply curve shifts to the right
At the original market price, a surplus! (qD<qS)
Some sellers willing to accept less at this quantity
More individuals want to sell more of the good at every price
Entire supply curve shifts to the right
At the original market price, a surplus! (qD<qS)
Some sellers willing to accept less at this quantity
Sellers lower asks, inducing buyers to buy more
Reach new equilibrium with:
Fewer individuals want to sell less of the good at every price
Entire supply curve shifts to the left
Fewer individuals want to sell less of the good at every price
Entire supply curve shifts to the left
At the original market price, a shortage! (qD>qS)
Fewer individuals want to sell less of the good at every price
Entire supply curve shifts to the left
At the original market price, a shortage! (qD>qS)
Some buyers willing to pay more at this quantity
Fewer individuals want to sell less of the good at every price
Entire supply curve shifts to the left
At the original market price, a shortage! (qD>qS)
Some buyers willing to pay more at this quantity
Buyers raise bids, inducing sellers to sell more
Reach new equilibrium with:
Markets allocate resources based on individuals' reservation prices:
Goods flow to those who value them the highest and away from those who value them the lowest
Markets allocate resources based on individuals' reservation prices:
Goods flow to those who value them the highest and away from those who value them the lowest
It might look like it, but competition in markets is NOT between buyers vs. sellers!
In markets: buyers compete with other buyers and sellers compete with other sellers
Buyers want to pay the lowest price to buy a good
But they face competition from other buyers over the same scarce goods
Buyers attempt to raise their bids above others' reservation prices to obtain the goods
Sellers want to get the highest price for a good they sell
But they face competition from other sellers over the same potential customers
Sellers attempt to lower their asking prices below others' reservation prices to sell their goods
Demand function measures how much you would hypothetically be willing to pay for various quantities
You often actually pay (the market-clearing price, p∗) a lot less than your reservation price
The difference is consumer surplus
CS=WTP−p∗
CS=12bhCS=12(5−0)($10−$5)CS=$12.50
CS′=12bhCS′=12(3−0)($10−$7)CS′=$4.50
CS′=12bhCS′=12(7−0)($10−$3)CS′=$24.50
CS=12bhCS=12(5−0)($10−$5)CS=$12.50
CS=12bhCS=12(5−0)($10−$5)CS=$12.50
CS=12bhCS=12(5−0)($7−$5)CS=$5.00
Supply function measures how much you would hypothetically be willing to accept to sell various quantities
You often actually receive (the market-clearing price, p∗) a lot more than your reservation price
The difference is producer surplus
PS=p∗−WTA
PS=12bhPS=12(5−0)($5−$0)PS=$12.50
PS′=12bhPS′=12(7−0)($7−$0)PS′=$24.50
PS′=12bhPS′=12(3−0)($3−$0)PS′=$4.50
PS=12bhPS=12(5−0)($5−$0)PS=$12.50
PS=12bhPS=12(5−0)($5−$0)PS=$12.50
PS=12bhPS=12(5−0)($5−$3)PS=$5.00
The more elastic curve at p∗ generates less surplus
The less elastic curve at p∗ generates more surplus
This is important for policies such as price controls, taxes, etc.
A good visual rule of thumb:
Compare distance between choke price and p∗ for each curve
Bigger distance ⟹ less elastic in equilibrium (and vice versa)
Example: Using last class's supply and demand functions:
qD=10−pqS=2p−8
Calculate the price elasticity of demand and the price elasticity of supply in equilibrium.
Calculate the consumer surplus and producer surplus. Shade each on the graph.
Who gets more surplus, consumers or producers, and why?
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |